The problem of optimal transport of mass from one distribution to another can be stated in many forms. Here is the formulation going back to Kantorovich: We have two measurable sets {\Omega_{1}} and {\Omega_{2}}, coming with two measures {\mu_{1}} and {\mu_{2}}. We also have a function {c:\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}\rightarrow {\mathbb R}} which assigns a transport cost, i.e. {c(x_{1},x_{2})} is the cost that it takes to carry one unit of mass from point {x_{1}\in\Omega_{2}} to {x_{2}\in\Omega_{2}}. What we want is a plan that says where the mass in {\mu_{1}} should be placed in {\Omega_{2}} (or vice versa). There are different ways to formulate this mathematically.

A simple way is to look for a map {T:\Omega_{1}\rightarrow\Omega_{2}} which says that thet mass in {x_{1}} should be moved to {T(x_{1})}. While natural, there is a serious problem with this: What if not all mass at {x_{1}} should go to the same point in {\Omega_{2}}? This happens in simple situations where all mass in {\Omega_{1}} sits in just one point, but there are at least two different points in {\Omega_{2}} where mass should end up. This is not going to work with a map {T} as above. So, the map {T} is not flexible enough to model all kinds of transport we may need.

What we want is a way to distribute mass from one point in {\Omega_{1}} to the whole set {\Omega_{2}}. This looks like we want maps {\mathcal{T}} which map points in {\Omega_{1}} to functions on {\Omega_{2}}, i.e. something like {\mathcal{T}:\Omega_{1}\rightarrow (\Omega_{2}\rightarrow{\mathbb R})} where {(\Omega_{2}\rightarrow{\mathbb R})} stands for some set of functions on {\Omega_{2}}. We can de-curry this function to some {\tau:\Omega_{1}\times\Omega_{2}\rightarrow{\mathbb R}} by {\tau(x_{1},x_{2}) = \mathcal{T}(x_{1})(x_{2})}. That’s good in principle, be we still run into problems when the target mass distribution {\mu_{2}} is singular in the sense that {\Omega_{2}} is a “continuous” set and there are single points in {\Omega_{2}} that carry some mass according to {\mu_{2}}. Since we are in the world of measure theory already, the way out suggests itself: Instead of a function {\tau} on {\Omega_{1}\times\Omega_{2}} we look for a measure {\pi} on {\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}} as a transport plan.

The demand that we should carry all of the mass in {\Omega_{1}} to reach all of {\mu_{2}} is formulated by marginals. For simplicity we just write these constraints as

\displaystyle \int_{\Omega_{2}}\pi\, d x_{2} = \mu_{1},\qquad \int_{\Omega_{1}}\pi\, d x_{1} = \mu_{2}

(with the understanding that the first equation really means that for all continuous function {f:\Omega_{1}\rightarrow {\mathbb R}} it holds that {\int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}} f(x_{1})\,d\pi(x_{1},x_{2}) = \int_{\Omega_{1}}f(x_{1})\,d\mu_{1}(x_{1})}).

This leads us to the full transport problem

\displaystyle \min_{\pi}\int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}c(x,y)\,d\pi(x_{1}x_{2})\quad \text{s.t.}\quad \int_{\Omega_{2}}\pi\, d x_{2} = \mu_{1},\quad \int_{\Omega_{1}}\pi\, d x_{1} = \mu_{2}.

There is the following theorem which characterizes optimality of a plan and which is the topic of this post:

Theorem 1 (Fundamental theorem of optimal transport) Under some technicalities we can say that a plan {\pi} which fulfills the marginal constraints is optimal if and only if one of the following equivalent conditions is satisfied:

  1. The support {\mathrm{supp}(\pi)} of {\pi} is {c}-cyclically monotone.
  2. There exists a {c}-concave function {\phi} such that its {c}-superdifferential contains the support of {\pi}, i.e. {\mathrm{supp}(\pi)\subset \partial^{c}\phi}.

 

A few clarifications: The technicalities involve continuity, integrability, and boundedness conditions of {c} and integrability conditions on the marginals. The full theorem can be found as Theorem 1.13 in A user’s guide to optimal transport by Ambrosio and Gigli. Also the notions {c}-cyclically monotone, {c}-concave and {c}-superdifferential probably need explanation. We start with a simpler notion: {c}-monotonicity:

Definition 2 A set {\Gamma\subset\Omega_{1}\times\Omega_{2}} is {c}-monotone, if for all {(x_{1}x_{2}),(x_{1}',x_{2}')\in\Gamma} it holds that

\displaystyle c(x_{1},x_{2}) + c(x_{1}',x_{2}')\leq c(x_{1},x_{2}') + c(x_{1}',x_{2}).

 

If you find it unclear what this has to do with monotonicity, look at this example:

Example 1 Let {\Omega_{1/2}\in{\mathbb R}^{d}} and let {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = \langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} be the usual scalar product. Then {c}-monotonicity is the condition that for all {(x_{1}x_{2}),(x_{1}',x_{2}')\in\Gamma\subset\Omega_{1}\times\Omega_{2}} it holds that

\displaystyle 0\leq \langle x_{1}-x_{1}',x_{2}-x_{2}'\rangle

which may look more familiar. Indeed, when {\Omega_{1}} and {\Omega_{2}} are subset of the real line, the above conditions means that the set {\Gamma} somehow “moves up in {\Omega_{2}}” if we “move right in {\Omega_{1}}”. So {c}-monotonicity for {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = \langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} is something like “monotonically increasing”. Similarly, for {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = -\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle}, {c}-monotonicity means “monotonically decreasing”.

You may say that both {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = \langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} and {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = -\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} are strange cost functions and I can’t argue with that. But here comes: {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = |x_{1}-x_{2}|^{2}} ({|\,\cdot\,|} being the euclidean norm) seems more natural, right? But if we have a transport plan {\pi} for this {c} for some marginals {\mu_{1}} and {\mu_{2}} we also have

\displaystyle \begin{array}{rcl} \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}c(x_{1},x_{2})d\pi(x_{1},x_{2}) & = & \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}|x_{1}|^{2} d\pi(x_{1},x_{2})\\ &&\quad- \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle d\pi(x_{1},x_{2})\\ && \qquad+ \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}} |x_{2}|^{2}d\pi(x_{1},x_{2})\\ & = &\int_{\Omega_{1}}|x_{1}|^{2}d\mu_{1}(x_{1}) - \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle d\pi(x_{1},x_{2}) + \int_{\Omega_{2}}|x_{2}|^{2}d\mu_{2}(x_{2}) \end{array}

i.e., the transport cost for {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = |x_{1}-x_{2}|^{2}} differs from the one for {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = -\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} only by a constant independent of {\pi}, so may well use the latter.

The fundamental theorem of optimal transport uses the notion of {c}-cyclical monotonicity which is stronger that just {c}-monotonicity:

Definition 3 A set {\Gamma\subset \Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}} is {c}-cyclically monotone, if for all {(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{i})\in\Gamma}, {i=1,\dots n} and all permutations {\sigma} of {\{1,\dots,n\}} it holds that

\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n}c(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{i}) \leq \sum_{i=1}^{n}c(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{\sigma(i)}).

 

For {n=2} we get back the notion of {c}-monotonicity.

Definition 4 A function {\phi:\Omega_{1}\rightarrow {\mathbb R}} is {c}-concave if there exists some function {\psi:\Omega_{2}\rightarrow{\mathbb R}} such that

\displaystyle \phi(x_{1}) = \inf_{x_{2}\in\Omega_{2}}c(x_{1},x_{2}) - \psi(x_{2}).

 

This definition of {c}-concavity resembles the notion of convex conjugate:

Example 2 Again using {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = -\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} we get that a function {\phi} is {c}-concave if

\displaystyle \phi(x_{1}) = \inf_{x_{2}}-\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle - \psi(x_{2}),

and, as an infimum over linear functions, {\phi} is clearly concave in the usual way.

Definition 5 The {c}-superdifferential of a {c}-concave function is

\displaystyle \partial^{c}\phi = \{(x_{1},x_{2})\mid \phi(x_{1}) + \phi^{c}(x_{2}) = c(x,y)\},

where {\phi^{c}} is the {c}-conjugate of {\phi} defined by

\displaystyle \phi^{c}(x_{2}) = \inf_{x_{1}\in\Omega_{1}}c(x_{1},x_{2}) -\phi(x_{1}).

 

Again one may look at {c(x_{1},x_{2}) = -\langle x_{1},x_{2}\rangle} and observe that the {c}-superdifferential is the usual superdifferential related to the supergradient of concave functions (there is a Wikipedia page for subgradient only, but the concept is the same with reversed signs in some sense).

Now let us sketch the proof of the fundamental theorem of optimal transport: \medskip

Proof (of the fundamental theorem of optimal transport). Let {\pi} be an optimal transport plan. We aim to show that {\mathrm{supp}(\pi)} is {c}-cyclically monotone and assume the contrary. That is, we assume that there are points {(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{i})\in\mathrm{supp}(\pi)} and a permutation {\sigma} such that

\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n}c(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{i}) > \sum_{i=1}^{n}c(x_{1}^{i},x_{2}^{\sigma(i)}).

We aim to construct a {\tilde\pi} such that {\tilde\pi} is still feasible but has a smaller transport cost. To do so, we note that continuity of {c} implies that there are neighborhoods {U_{i}} of {x_{1}^{i}} and {V_{i}} of {x_{2}^{i}} such that for all {u_{i}\in U_{1}} and {v_{i}\in V_{i}} it holds that

\displaystyle \sum_{i=1}^{n}c(u_{i},v_{\sigma(i)}) - c(u_{i},v_{i})<0.

We use this to construct a better plan {\tilde \pi}: Take the mass of {\pi} in the sets {U_{i}\times V_{i}} and shift it around. The full construction is a little messy to write down: Define a probability measure {\nu} on the product {X = \bigotimes_{i=1}^{N}U_{i}\times V_{i}} as the product of the measures {\tfrac{1}{\pi(U_{i}\times V_{i})}\pi|_{U_{i}\times V_{i}}}. Now let {P^{U_{1}}} and {P^{V_{i}}} be the projections of {X} onto {U_{i}} and {V_{i}}, respectively, and set

\displaystyle \nu = \tfrac{\min_{i}\pi(U_{i}\times V_{i})}{n}\sum_{i=1}^{n}(P^{U_{i}},P^{V_{\sigma(i)}})_{\#}\nu - (P^{U_{i}},P^{V_{i}})_{\#}\nu

where {_{\#}} denotes the pushforward of measures. Note that the new measure {\nu} is signed and that {\tilde\pi = \pi + \nu} fulfills

  1. {\tilde\pi} is a non-negative measure
  2. {\tilde\pi} is feasible, i.e. has the correct marginals
  3. {\int c\,d\tilde \pi<\int c\,d\pi}

which, all together, gives a contradiction to optimality of {\pi}. The implication of item 1 to item 2 of the theorem is not really related to optimal transport but a general fact about {c}-concavity and {c}-cyclical monotonicity (c.f.~this previous blog post of mine where I wrote a similar statement for convexity). So let us just prove the implication from item 2 to optimality of {\pi}: Let {\pi} fulfill item 2, i.e. {\pi} is feasible and {\mathrm{supp}(\pi)} is contained in the {c}-superdifferential of some {c}-concave function {\phi}. Moreover let {\tilde\pi} be any feasible transport plan. We aim to show that {\int c\,d\pi\leq \int c\,d\tilde\pi}. By definition of the {c}-superdifferential and the {c}-conjugate we have

\displaystyle \begin{array}{rcl} \phi(x_{1}) + \phi^{c}(x_{2}) &=& c(x_{1},x_{2})\ \forall (x_{1},x_{2})\in\partial^{c}\phi\\ \phi(x_{1}) + \phi^{c}(x_{2}) & \leq& c(x_{1},x_{2})\ \forall (x_{1},x_{2})\in\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}. \end{array}

Since {\mathrm{supp}(\pi)\subset\partial^{c}\phi} by assumption, this gives

\displaystyle \begin{array}{rcl} \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}c(x_{1},x_{2})\,d\pi(x_{1},x_{2}) & =& \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}\phi(x_{1}) + \phi^{c}(x_{1})\,d\pi(x_{1},x_{2})\\ &=& \int_{\Omega_{1}}\phi(x_{1})\,d\mu_{1}(x_{1}) + \int_{\Omega_{1}}\phi^{c}(x_{2})\,d\mu_{2}(x_{2})\\ &=& \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}\phi(x_{1}) + \phi^{c}(x_{1})\,d\tilde\pi(x_{1},x_{2})\\ &\leq& \int_{\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}}c(x_{1},x_{2})\,d\tilde\pi(x_{1},x_{2}) \end{array}

which shows the claim.

{\Box}

Corollary 6 If {\pi} is a measure on {\Omega_{1}\times \Omega_{2}} which is supported on a {c}-superdifferential of a {c}-concave function, then {\pi} is an optimal transport plan for its marginals with respect to the transport cost {c}.